I've finally made my way through Neil
Irwin's The Alchemists, and
it's been a worthwhile trip. Well: it's been a long slog actually,
but that remark isn't nearly as negative as it may sound. In many
ways it's a very good book, sometimes spectacularly good. And while
it has its limitations, I have to admit I'd be hard put to know how
to make it much better.
Anybody
who reads this far will already know the terms of engagement: Irwin
proposes to bring us up to date on three central bankers: Ben
Bernanke (of course); Jean-Claude Trichet, president of the European
Central Bank from 2003 to 2011; and Mervin King, governor of the Bank
of England from 2003 to just this year. In short, the three most
powerful voices in banking during the late uproar (for extra credit:
who is the Ben Bernanke of China?).
It's a
promising framework and it almost works, with the qualification that
the institutional limits on Trichet were strong enough that it makes
him hard to compare. And like it or not—the Brits will not like
it—the hard fact is that Britain comes across as a second-tier
player, mostly mired in its own problems, sometimes buffeted by its
larger neighbors.
There's
an additional problem that I will specify in the moment, but first
the good stuff: Within the limits of the engagement, Irwin has done a
splendid job of marshaling and presenting so much abstruse material.
Clearly, his time out at Columbia Business School served him well:
he's got a (seemingly) easy mastery of arcanae of central banking,
with a good teacher's knack for making the tough stuff accessible.
If nothing else, you could do worse than pull this one down whenever
you need to pretend that you understand the virtues and limitations
of, say, inflation targeting or the twist. [Just as an aside: would
I be right that financial journalism has improved markedly since
2008? Back in the old days, we had Greg Ip: now we have half dozen
or more first-stringers who can go pretty much toe to with their
sources. Brad DeLong likes to ask why we can't have a better press
core. I wonder if maybe we have one).,
There's
a limitation, as I've already suggested, in that the three stories
are not quite comparable: even though they overlap, each faced his
own issues with his own tools and institutional limitations. A
bigger problem is the focus on central banking. For good or ill, the
point (which the book makes abundantly clear) is that central banking
could serve at best as only part of the solution. If you're an
American reader, you probably already understand that; you whatever
fiscal policy emerged in Washington between 2008 and today was a
joint effort of the Fed and Treasury. You can't really blame Irwin
for not telling the whole story—his book would have been twice as
long and many times as unwieldy had he tried—but you really are
getting only part of the picture without it. The European situation
is even stranger, what with its multiple sovereignties and its single
currency. I don't feel I have much of a handle on it, but my
consolation is I really don't think anybody else does either. The
British experience is simpler, but perhaps starker. King seems to
have been unconstrained about dipping his finger into the political
pot (you get the impression that Irwin really doesn't like King very
much). British leaders do seem to have made some catastrophically
bad decisions lately, but for the most part, hey, it's only Britain
and how much can it matter?
In
short, I'm just as glad Irwin didn't try to tell us "the full
story.” But if we want “the full story,” we'd better have
read—or be prepared to read—somebody else.
A
difficulty, less important than the others, but it may account for my
feelings of slog. Irwin shares a vice with a number of
journalists-turned-bookies, and that is: the closer you get to the
present, the more you feel like you are reading the pages of his
notebook, the less you get by way of sustained analysis. At times, I
found myself remembering what Dr. Johnson said about Paradise
Lost. On the other hand, I'm
glad I read that one, too.
No comments:
Post a Comment